National Academies Press: OpenBook

Measuring Poverty: A New Approach (1995)

Chapter: 8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC

« Previous: 7 Use of the Poverty Measure in Government Assistance Programs
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 335
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 336
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 337
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 338
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 339
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 340
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 341
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 342
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 343
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 344
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 345
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 346
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 347
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 348
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 349
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 350
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 351
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 352
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 353
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 354
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 355
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 356
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 357
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 358
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 359
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 360
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 361
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 362
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 363
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 364
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 365
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 366
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 367
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 368
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 369
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 370
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 371
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 372
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 373
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 374
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 375
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 376
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 377
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 378
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 379
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 380
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 381
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 382
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 383
Suggested Citation:"8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 384

Below is the uncorrected machine-read text of this chapter, intended to provide our own search engines and external engines with highly rich, chapter-representative searchable text of each book. Because it is UNCORRECTED material, please consider the following text as a useful but insufficient proxy for the authoritative book pages.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 335 8 The Poverty Measure and AFDC In addition to reviewing the statistical measure of poverty, the panel was asked to consider issues of benefit levels for government family assistance programs—in particular, a national minimum benefit standard for the Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) program. Currently, there are large differences in AFDC benefit standards across states, and no state provides benefits as generous as the official poverty thresholds. Federal policy makers have several times considered enacting a uniform minimum benefit standard that would provide a nationwide floor for AFDC benefits. The congressional debate over the Family Support Act (FSA) of 1988 included proposals for a national minimum benefit, but they were not accepted, largely because of the sizable estimated budgetary costs to the government. The FSA did request a study of minimum benefit standards, however, and this chapter responds to that request. We considered conceptual and statistical issues involved in setting a national minimum benefit standard for AFDC, just as we considered such issues for the poverty line. In our review, we focused on the nature of the relationship between program benefit levels (whether in AFDC or other cash and near-cash assistance programs) and a measure of poverty (whether ours or another), and we show why that relationship is indirect at best. We also considered the relationship of the proposed poverty measure to AFDC standards of need. AFDC is unique among cash and near-cash assistance programs in that the states are required to establish a standard of need but are not required to—and often do not—use this standard to determine actual benefits. (See Appendix D for details of the AFDC program.)

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 336 DETERMINING PROGRAM BENEFIT LEVELS We recommend (in Chapter 7) that serious consideration be given to the use of the proposed poverty measure as an eligibility standard for programs that tie eligibility for benefits and services to the current poverty measure. It might seem a logical next step to suggest a direct relationship of the proposed poverty measure to program benefits. Certainly, the existence of a poverty threshold that makes reasonable adjustments for differences in family circumstances, including differences in the cost of living across regions of the country, creates an impetus for program benefits to be related to that threshold. However, there are many factors that properly enter into a determination of benefit levels, only one of which is a poverty threshold. At present, there is wide variation in AFDC benefits across the 50 states and the District of Columbia, and, in most states, benefits are considerably below the official poverty threshold. As of January 1994, the states' median standard of need for a three-person family was 60 percent of the corresponding official poverty threshold, and the median maximum benefit was 38 percent of the poverty threshold.1 The median of the maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefit for the states was 69 percent of the poverty threshold. Looking across states, the maximum AFDC benefit for a three-person family in January 1994 varied from $923 per month in Alaska to $120 in Mississippi, with a median of $366, a mean of $396, and a coefficient of variation of 40 percent; see Table 8-1.2 The maximum AFDC benefit ranged from $240 to $552 (25-58% of the poverty threshold) in about two-thirds of the states; eight states exceeded this range, and eight states fell below it. The maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefit for a three-person family exhibited somewhat less dispersion, varying from $1,208 in Alaska to $415 in Mississippi, with a median of $658, a mean of $675, and a coefficient of variation of 22 percent. Food stamps have this effect because of the program's benefit formula, which assumes that families will devote 30 percent of their countable income to food expenditures (see Chapter 7). Hence, an increase of $1 in AFDC benefits (or other countable income) decreases food stamp benefits by 30 cents, and a decrease of $1 in AFDC benefits (or other countable income) increases food stamp benefits by 30 cents. The maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefit ranged from $528 to $822 (55-86% of the poverty threshold) in 39 states. Adjusting AFDC and food stamp benefit levels to take account of differences in the cost of living by state further reduces the variation, although only to a limited extent (see below). 1 The three-person family (parent or caretaker and two children) is the usual reference family for AFDC. 2 The coefficient of variation is the standard deviation of a distribution as a percentage of the mean value; the standard deviation is the value that when added to or subtracted from the mean includes about two-thirds of the observations (states in this case).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 337 TABLE 8-1 AFDC Need Standards, Maximum AFDC Benefits, and Maximum Combined AFDC and Food Stamp Benefits for a Family of Three, January 1994 Maximum AFDC Maximum Combined Benefit AFDC/Food Stamp Benefit State AFDC Dollar Percent of Dollar Percent of Need Value Need Value Need Standard Alabama 673 164 24 459 68 Alaska 975 923 95 1,208 124 Arizona 964 347 36 639 66 Arkansas 705 204 29 499 71 California 715 607 85 821 115 Colorado 421 356 85 645 153 Connecticut 680 680 100 872 128 Delaware 338 338 100 633 187 District of 712 420 59 690 97 Columbia Florida 991 303 31 598 60 Georgia 424 280 66 575 136 Hawaii 1,140 712 62 1,134 99 Idaho 991 317 32 612 62 Illinois 890 367 41 658 74 Indiana 320 288 90 583 182 Iowa 849 426 50 694 82 Kansas 429 429 100 713 166 Kentucky 526 228 43 523 99 Louisiana 658 190 29 485 74 Maine 553 418 76 689 125 Maryland 507 366 72 661 130 Massachusetts 579 579 100 801 138 Michigan a 551 459 83 717 130 Minnesota 532 532 100 768 144 Mississippi 368 120 33 415 113 Missouri 846 292 35 587 69 Montana 511 401 78 677 132 Nebraska 364 364 100 651 179 Nevada 699 348 50 640 92 New Hampshire 1,648 550 33 781 47 New Jersey 985 424 43 700 71 New Mexico 357 357 100 646 181 New Yorkb 577 577 100 816 141 North Carolina 544 272 50 567 104 North Dakota 409 409 100 682 167 Ohio 879 341 39 636 72 Oklahoma 471 324 69 619 131 Oregon 460 460 100 753 164 Pennsylvania 614 421 69 691 113

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 338 Maximum AFDC Benefit Maximum Combined AFDC/Food Stamp Benefit State AFDC Dollar Percent of Dollar Percent of Need Value Need Value Need Standard Rhode Island 554 554 100 822 148 South Carolina 440 200 45 495 113 South Dakota 491 417 85 688 140 Tennessee 426 185 43 480 113 Texas 574 184 32 479 83 Utah 552 414 75 686 124 Vermont 1,124 638 57 843 75 Virginia 393 354 90 644 164 Washington 1,158 546 47 804 69 West Virginia 497 249 50 544 109 Wisconsin 647 517 80 758 117 Wyoming 674 360 53 648 96 Mean 655 396 66 675 115 Median 574 366 66 658 113 Range 320–1,648 120–923 24–100 415– 47–187 1,208 Coefficient of 40.7% 39.5% 39.6% 21.8% 32.5% variationc SOURCE: U.S. House of Representatives (1994:366-367). a The values apply to Wayne County. b The values apply to New York City. c The standard deviation of the distribution as a percentage of the mean value. Proposals for AFDC Minimum Benefits: A Brief History The original Aid to Dependent Children program, the predecessor to AFDC, was enacted in 1935 as part of the legislation that instituted a national Social Security system.3 It was designed to put on a sounder footing the states' programs to provide ''mothers' pensions," but there was no intent to mandate a prominent role for the federal government.4 The legislation provided that the federal government would pay 33 percent of the program's costs, with a 3 Peterson and Rom (1990:Chap. 4) is the main source for this historical review; see also U.S. Senate (1986). 4 In contrast, it was argued in the case of Social Security that national standards were needed to protect working people, given the mobility of labor across state boundaries. Similarly, for unemployment insurance, it was argued that a nationally uniform payroll tax was needed to ensure that states could not gain an unfair business advantage by choosing not to provide unemployment compensation.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 339 maximum federal payment of $6 a month for the first child and $4 for other children. In 1950 the program was amended to provide benefits to the mother herself (or another caretaker of a dependent child or children), and in 1962 the program was amended to provide benefits (at state discretion) to two-parent families in which both were unemployed. The original legislation required that the states pay one-third of the costs (i.e., it prohibited states from the common practice of laying off all their costs on local jurisdictions), and it made federal payments "conditional on passage and enforcement of mandatory State laws and on the submission of approved plans assuring minimum standards in investigation, amounts of grants, and administration" (Congressional Record, January 17, 1935:548). Since one-half of the counties in the United States did not provide mothers' pensions at the time and there was wide variation in payments across counties within states, the legislation had the effect of reducing within-state variation in benefits. However, it had little effect on across state variation, leaving broad discretion to the states to set need standards, payments, and eligibility rules. For example, states were allowed to keep their residency requirements, and most did so until the Supreme Court in 1969 ruled them to be unconstitutional. Historically, reformers have followed three strategies to try to establish more uniform state policies with regard to AFDC benefits (see Peterson and Rom, 1990:99-100), focusing on the matching formula, a supplementary national program, and national minimum benefit standards. The Matching Formula The federal matching percentage was raised from 33 to 50 percent in 1939, to be consistent with the percentage for programs to assist the needy elderly, blind, and disabled. The formula was changed several times more between 1944 and 1958. Finally, in 1965, states were given the option of switching to the matching formula adopted for the Medicaid program. This formula committed the federal government to paying at least 50 percent of the welfare benefit in every state and to paying a higher matching rate (up to 83%) in those states with lower per capita income. Currently, all states use the Medicaid matching formula for AFDC benefits. The matching percentages in fiscal 1994 varied from 50-55 percent in 19 states and the District of Columbia to 70-79 percent in 13 states (U.S. House of Representatives, 1994: Table 10-17). The rationale for the changes in the matching formula included the desire to provide incentives for low-benefit states to raise their benefits. However, Peterson and Rom (1990) found that the differences in benefit levels across states remained essentially unchanged, with a coefficient of variation that ranged from 34 to 37 percent in each decade from the 1940s to the 1980s. A Supplementary Program with a National Benefit Standard —Food Stamps Food assistance programs in the United States were initially very

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 340 localized. Many communities did not participate in the food stamp (or commodity distribution) program, and eligibility standards varied widely among those that did. In 1970 the Food Stamp Program was effectively nationalized: a single national standard was adopted, which was higher than any then in use in the states; the Secretary of Agriculture was empowered to set national eligibility requirements; and stiff penalties could be imposed on states that did not operate a program in every county. In 1977 Congress eliminated all purchase requirements for food stamps, making them a simple supplement to cash assistance in inverse proportion to family income (as well as a benefit to working families not receiving cash assistance). The effect of these changes was to reduce the variation across states in the combined value of AFDC and food stamp benefits. However, there was no incentive for low-benefit states to raise AFDC benefits per se; rather the provision that food stamp benefits increase (decrease) by 30 cents for every dollar decrease (increase) in cash benefits in effect rewarded states that kept cash benefits low and penalized states that increased them. A National Minimum Benefit Standard for AFDC The strategy of legislating a uniform minimum benefit standard for AFDC has never achieved legislative success. In an early discussion of needed reforms in public assistance programs, Leon Keyserling's Conference on Economic Progress (1959:58) urged that "minimum uniform standards among the States should be set by the Federal Government." In 1965, the Office of Economic Opportunity (OEO) proposed a negative income tax program with a single nationwide payment schedule as part of its first "national anti-poverty plan." As part of its second plan in 1966, OEO again proposed a negative income tax program with a single nationwide payment schedule; besides being available to all poor persons without regard to demographic category, this proposed program would have gradually replaced existing public assistance programs (including AFDC) by 1972. In that same year the Advisory Council on Public Welfare (1966:15,22,117) recommended a "minimum standard for public assistance payments below which no State may fall." It proposed (p. xii) that the ''Federal Government … set nationwide standards, adjusted by objective criteria to varying costs and conditions among the States, and assume the total cost of their implementation above a stipulated State share." In 1967 President Johnson proposed that states be required to pay 100 percent of their standard of need, but he did not propose any specific minimum benefit standard. The proposal was rejected in the House Ways and Means Committee. The President's Commission on Income Maintenance (1969:7) recommended a "universal income supplement program financed and administered by the Federal Government." Concerning benefit levels for this income supplement program, the Commission stated (p. 59) that "attempts to reflect different costs of living in different areas would involve many difficulties and so a uniform National supplement is recommended."

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 341 The Family Assistance Plan (FAP) put forward by the Nixon Administration in the late 1960s provided for two kinds of programs, each with national minimum benefit standards: a program for low-income elderly, blind, and disabled (which subsequently became the Supplemental Security Income [SSI] program), and a program for all families with dependent children, regardless of work status. The proposed FAP AFDC minimum benefit was $1,600 a year for a family of four (about 40% of the official poverty line at that time)—a level that would have raised benefits in 16 states. FAP passed the House in 1970 but died in the Senate: conservatives questioned the adequacy of the work incentives; liberals criticized the national minimum benefit as inadequate. The Carter Administration's Better Jobs and Income Program, proposed as legislation in 1977, also included a national minimum benefit for a program that would have combined AFDC, SSI, and food stamps; the minimum was set at $4,200 for a family of four whose head could not be expected to work (about 70% of the poverty line). This proposal died in Congress. In 1979 a scaled-back plan was introduced that proposed a national minimum benefit for AFDC at about 75 percent of the poverty line. The House passed this plan with the minimum benefit lowered to 65 percent of the poverty line (which would have raised benefits in 13 states). This bill died in the Senate. As noted above, proposals for a national minimum benefit were originally considered for the 1988 FSA. In 1987 the House Ways and Means Committee approved a minimum benefit standard, but opposition from southern Democrats on the grounds of increased costs to their states resulted in stripping this provision from the legislation. The FSA instead mandated a study of minimum benefit standards. Issues in Program Benefit Design Today, the de facto national minimum level of available benefits for AFDC recipients is the maximum food stamp allowance combined with the maximum AFDC benefit in the lowest benefit state. In January 1994, this amount was $415 per month for a three-person family, or 43 percent of the corresponding poverty threshold. Hence, the issue of a national minimum benefit standard for AFDC really comes down to an issue of raising this de facto standard. Arguments for adopting such a nationwide minimum benefit standard for AFDC have been made on the basis of equity: that low-income families with children should not be disadvantaged simply by reason of their state of residence. In addition, others have argued that differences in benefits encourage low-income families to migrate from low-benefit to high-benefit states. There have been studies of the migration effects of AFDC, but they suffer from serious data and methodological problems. The results suggest that there is an effect on the migration behavior of low-income families but that the effect, for a number of reasons, is quite weak (see below).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 342 We considered the issue of a national minimum benefit standard in somewhat broader terms, asking the question of how or if the proposed poverty measure could or should be linked with benefit levels for a program such as AFDC or a combination of AFDC and other cash and near-cash assistance programs. We first broached this issue in Chapter 7 , in which we discussed the possible use of the proposed poverty measure for programs that already relate eligibility to the current measure. We pointed out some of the reasons that program agencies might want to make the link less direct, for example, by setting eligibility cutoffs at a fraction of the poverty thresholds. Here we explore more fully the reasons that a program benefit standard could differ from a poverty standard and, more generally, why the design of an assistance program could deviate from the goal of helping everyone who is classified as poor. A note on terminology: When we speak of a "benefit standard" in the context of AFDC, we mean what is referred to in that program as the "maximum benefit" in contrast to either the ''need standard" or the "payment standard." A family must have gross income below 185 percent of the need standard to be eligible for AFDC; it must also have net or countable income below 100 percent of the payment standard. A number of states have a payment standard below their need standard, and some states cap the maximum benefit at a lower level than the payment standard (see below). The measurement of poverty or need does not necessarily imply anything about the extent to which need can or should be alleviated through government assistance programs. There are five key issues that separate measurement of need and alleviation of need: budget constraints, both overall and from competing demands on funding resources; strategies and preferences for targeting program benefits; interactions among programs; behavioral responses to program incentives; and, finally, cost-sharing provisions for federal-state programs. Budget Constraints Scarce budget resources may well limit the extent to which benefit standards can approach the poverty threshold, particularly in entitlement programs, such as AFDC, that must provide benefits to all eligible applicants. Both globally and in the United States, the areas with the greatest poverty are typically the areas that can least afford high benefits. For example, in some African countries, such a high proportion of the population is poor (by any standard) that very few resources are available internally to alleviate poverty. For AFDC, the states with low-benefit standards tend to be the states with higher poverty rates and with lower per capita incomes and, hence, with less ability to provide assistance to their needy families. Thus, maximum benefits in January 1990 were negatively correlated with the 1989 state poverty rate

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 343 (correlation coefficient, –.55) and positively correlated with the 1989 state per capita income (correlation coefficient, .67).5 However, there is considerable variation in benefit levels among the states that is not explained by differences in income. Peterson and Rom (1989) and Plotnick and Winters (1985) show that differences in AFDC benefits across states relate to a variety of political, ethnic, and economic differences. For the nation as a whole, it would be hard to argue that the United States lacks sufficient revenue-generating ability to provide assistance to families below the poverty level. But the country's funding resources are not unlimited, and there are many demands on them. Assistance programs must compete with all other uses of taxpayers' funds. Targeting Strategies and Preferences In order to maximize the effectiveness of limited funds and achieve other policy goals, there may be reasons to target assistance payments to particular groups, even though simple measurement of need would not necessarily identify them as unique. For example, because of the long-term social cost of children growing up in economic deprivation, it may be sensible to concentrate assistance dollars on poor families with children, even though other groups have need that is just as great. There are many examples of targeting in current programs. The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) was originally targeted to working poor families with children and was recently expanded to cover childless workers as well (see Appendix D). Food stamps offers another example of targeting, in that the program is designed to provide a more secure safety net for the elderly and disabled than for other people. This feature operates through the definition of countable income, which permits more generous deductions for households with elderly and disabled members in determining eligibility and benefits. Also, there is a higher asset limit for households with an elderly member (see Appendix D). Another approach would be to concentrate scarce assistance dollars on the poorest families (the "worst off" among the poor), even though helping the families closest to the poverty line (the "best off" among the poor) would achieve the fastest reduction in measured need. In other words, although the strategy of helping the poorest poor will not produce as large a reduction in measured need per dollar spent as helping other poor people, it may be the best strategy to reduce poverty. 5 The correlations were carried out by using data on AFDC benefits from U.S. House of Representatives (1990:553-555) and data on state poverty rates and per capita incomes from the 1990 census (Bureau of the Census, 1993d: Tables 733, 741).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 344 Program Interactions The existence of multiple assistance programs can affect the level of the benefit standard that makes sense for any one of them. For example, AFDC interacts with food stamps and public housing, and it makes little sense to think of an AFDC benefit standard in isolation from these programs (or in isolation from such programs as the EITC and enforcement of child support). However, given the different ways in which eligibility and benefits are calculated, it is not easy to determine an appropriate adjustment to AFDC benefit levels to take account of program interactions. In the case of AFDC and food stamps, for example, one could certainly argue for excluding food costs from the AFDC benefit standard because of the almost universal provision of food stamps (and school meals) to AFDC families. As noted above, it would also be to a state's financial benefit to reduce its AFDC benefit standard by as much as the value of the Thrifty Food Plan because the Food Stamp Program will provide higher benefits than otherwise would have been the case. However, only in the case of states with very low AFDC benefit standards will the Food Stamp Program in fact make up the entire difference for recipients. This occurs because the program assumes that, after deductions, 30 percent of countable income including AFDC benefits is available for food consumption and, hence, reduces food stamp benefits accordingly. As a hypothetical example, consider a state that wants to provide combined AFDC and food stamp benefits at the level of the official poverty threshold. The deductions in the Food Stamp Program make it difficult to calculate by how much the state should reduce its AFDC benefit standard, but it can be demonstrated that not to reduce the AFDC standard at all may overcompensate recipients by as much as 10 percent relative to the poverty threshold, while to reduce the AFDC standard by the full amount of the Thrifty Food Plan may undercompensate recipients by as much as 17 percent.6 Program interactions virtually dictate that designers of assistance programs use complicated models to evaluate likely program effects. Some models are designed to point out odd interactions of such program features as maximum benefit levels and tax rates on other income by estimating the benefit package 6 The first bound is obtained as follows: assume the AFDC benefit standard is $991 per month, or 100 percent of the poverty guideline for a family of three in 1993 (no state actually paid this amount). Then a family with the maximum $991 benefit from AFDC and the standard and excess shelter deductions for food stamps would have $653 of countable food stamp income and would receive $99 in food stamps (the Thrifty Food Plan value of $295 minus 30% of $653), for a total combined benefit of $991 plus $99, or $1,090 (110% of the poverty guideline). To obtain the other result, assume that the same state reduced its benefit standard to $696 by subtracting the entire value of the Thrifty Food Plan. Then a family with the maximum $696 AFDC benefit but only the standard food stamp deduction would have $565 in countable food stamp income and would receive $125 in food stamps ($295 minus 30% of $565), for a total combined benefit of $696 plus $125, or $821 (83% of the poverty guideline).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 345 that would accrue to a specific type of family at a particular income level. Other models use microsimulation techniques operating on large-scale household databases to project the effects on program costs and caseloads of specified program features, given the distribution of the population and estimates of the likelihood of participation and other behavioral effects (see Citro and Hanushek, 1991; Lewis and Michel, 1990). Program Incentives Human beings participate in programs, and programs undeniably affect their behavior. Some effects are intended, others are unintended; some effects are positive, others are negative. Some programs have an explicit goal of providing a positive incentive: for example, the federal government subsidizes student loans to encourage more young people to obtain the economic and other benefits of a college education. As another example, the Special Supplemental Nutrition Program for Women, Infants, and Children (WIC) seeks out poor pregnant women, mothers, and children to provide food supplements with the goal of healthier pregnancies, healthier babies, and, ultimately, healthier children and adults. Other programs have a primary goal of providing income support to needy people. Such cash and near-cash assistance programs as AFDC and food stamps must contend with the fact that economic support has negative incentive effects to the extent that recipients are encouraged to rely on the program and not take steps to become self-supporting. Research on AFDC has examined incentive effects in the areas of work effort, family structure, and migration. Work Effects Both economic theory and empirical research indicate that such programs as AFDC adversely affect the work choices of the eligible population. These programs provide a "guaranteed" base income to those who do not work; the resulting "income effect" allows individuals to work less. These programs also impose taxes on earned income. Since workers' net wages are now lower, the "substitution effect" encourages them to decrease the number of hours worked as it is relatively less expensive for them to do so. The combination of these provisions results in an unambiguous decrease in the aggregate number of hours of market work by the eligible low-income population.7 Extensive research has been undertaken to estimate the magnitude of the 7 In theory, there is an alternative explanation: it is possible that the primary effect of extra program dollars for low-income families is to induce them to underreport their earned (or other) income. That is, rather than decreasing work hours, they may decrease reporting of work hours (or switch to work where it is easier to evade official notice). However, there is no empirical evidence on this point.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 346 reduction in work resulting from the disincentives embedded in assistance programs (see Danziger, Haveman, and Plotnick, 1981, and Moffitt, 1992, for extensive literature reviews on the subject). Although evidence shows that AFDC reduces the number of hours worked by single mothers, the estimates of those reductions vary among studies—from 1 to 10 hours per week. Moffitt (1992), in his review of the literature, concludes that "there is still considerable uncertainty regarding the magnitude of the effects." Moffitt (1992) points out that there is very little research on the effects of in-kind assistance on labor supply.8 He also notes the importance of exploring the effects of multiple assistance programs; however, these effects are difficult to model, and little work has been done in the area. Family Structure Decisions Much of the literature on family structure focuses on whether AFDC encourages the formation of single-parent families headed by women. Since benefits are targeted to mothers with children and no spouse present, they may provide incentives to delay marriage or remarriage, to obtain a divorce, or to have children outside of marriage. Early work looking at the effect of AFDC on the increase in female-headed families is extremely mixed (see the summary in Groeneveld, Hannan, and Tuma, 1983). Studies in the 1980s, however, show more consistent evidence of an effect (see Danziger et al., 1982; Ellwood and Bane, 1985; Hoffman and Duncan, 1988; Moffitt, 1992). There is also some evidence of an effect of AFDC benefit levels on the probability that a female head lives independently rather than in a larger family (see Ellwood and Bane, 1985; Hutchens, Jakubson, and Schwartz, 1989). Extensive research has been done on the effect of AFDC on illegitimacy. The work has studied whether the existence of public assistance increases the chances that babies will be born to unmarried women since a woman no longer needs a husband to help support a child. The work has also considered whether the existence of public assistance increases the likelihood that a woman will have a child in order to become eligible for benefits at all or have another child in order to receive additional benefits. The evidence on this issue in the literature is inconclusive: some studies find effects for some groups (e.g., white or black teenagers), and others find no effects for the same groups (see Duncan and Hoffman, 1990; Ellwood and Bane, 1985; An, Haveman, and Wolfe, 1991; Lundburg and Plotnick, 1990; Plotnick, 1990). Migration Effects The extent to which the wide variation in AFDC benefit levels across states influences patterns of interstate migration is of 8 See Fraker and Moffitt (1988) on the disincentive effects of the Food Stamp Program on the labor supply of female heads. Blank (1989), Moffitt and Wolfe (1990), and Winkler (1989) have analyzed the labor supply effects of the Medicaid program on the Medicaid- eligible population.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 347 particular relevance to the issue of a nationwide minimum benefit standard. Hence, we considered it in some detail. Substantial cross-state differentials in AFDC benefits have existed since the inception of the AFDC program, but they have created greater policy concern since residency requirements were ruled unconstitutional in 1969. In particular, policy makers (particularly in high-benefit states) have worried that their states attract welfare recipients, thereby increasing the burden on taxpayers. A simple comparison of the expected income available to AFDC- eligible families in highand low-benefit states clearly indicates that such families can receive more income in a high-benefit state, which should create an incentive for them to relocate. Since the same states have generally remained high- or low-benefit states, if such migration occurs, it should have been steadily occurring in about the same regional patterns throughout the past 25 years. There are, however, at least three reasons why such an effect might be small or not exist at all. First, moving costs money. Not only are there actual transportation costs associated with moving, but families that migrate will often have to pay a security deposit for a new apartment, experience some transitional time during which they are neither working nor on AFDC, and bear the myriad of costs associated with relocation to a new city and residence. Low-income families may be least able to bear these moving costs. Second, families—and particularly low-income women—may lack information about their income opportunities in distant state locations. States do not generally advertise their AFDC benefit levels, and unless women have other sources of information (such as friends or relatives in another location), they may have only a hazy idea about alternative benefit levels. Third, relocation decisions are affected by many things other than income expectations. In particular, especially for low-income women with children, there may be substantial nonmonetary costs to moving. The presence of family and friends in their current location may provide many benefits: friends and family can provide free baby-sitting services, can be a source of shared resources in hard economic times, and can be an important source of psychological support. In addition, women with children might be quite risk- averse about relocating their children to an unknown low-income neighborhood, with concerns about school, crime, and gangs. For many women, these nonmonetary costs might be large enough that they completely swamp any differences in expected income levels. These arguments indicate that the expected effects of AFDC benefit levels on migration behavior among low-income women with children are probably small, at least in part because this is a population that one would expect to be less mobile than many others. On the margin, however, one may still expect that AFDC benefits would have a positive effect on migration probabilities. In order to measure the size of any welfare-induced migration, one ideally

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 348 would have longitudinal data that track family location decisions. The data would also contain information on women's expectations and their economic opportunities in alternative locations, including not only what they know about alternative AFDC benefit levels in different locations, but also what they know about wage and employment opportunities. The need to have control variables available on non-AFDC economic opportunities is particularly important, since state AFDC benefit levels are positively correlated with state income and wage levels. (This is not surprising, given that only high-income states can afford to pay high AFDC benefits and that only states with high wage levels can pay high AFDC benefits without creating large work disincentives.) Finally, the data would contain information on whether women have friends, family, or any other source of support or contacts within alternative state locations. (For example, knowing if a woman or her parents have ever lived in another state would be one way of controlling for the nonmonetary costs of choosing a different location.) Unfortunately, a national data set with such information does not exist. The empirical research has been based on much more limited data, and, as a result, the quality of most the analyses is suspect (see Moffitt, 1992, for a review of the literature). Despite the problems, however, two conclusions are warranted: migration rates among AFDC recipients are quite low, and there is a small positive effect of AFDC benefits on the probability of migrating to (or not migrating out of) a high-benefit state (see, e.g., Blank, 1988; Clark, 1988, 1990, 1992; Gramlich and Laren, 1984; however, Peterson and Rom, 1989, find larger effects). The results are convincing not because any one of the studies is very well done, but because studies done in different ways with very different types of errors all point in the same direction. The research suggests that welfare-induced migration should be a second- order concern for policy makers. For states that have large populations very close to each other, large benefit differences may indeed induce a migration flow. However, on average, the effects of AFDC benefits on migration are small and movement among the AFDC population is infrequent. The fact that different states have had long-term AFDC benefit differentials that are very large and have been very large for many years is perhaps further evidence that migration effects are hard to discern in the data. Although states may talk about this problem, high-benefit states have not been concerned enough about it (with a few exceptions) to cut their benefits relative to other states. There is a lot that is not known about migration effects. There is little or no evidence on the propensity to use AFDC by recent migrants in comparison with natives in a state; on the comparative duration of their AFDC spells if they do become recipients; or on the effects of AFDC benefits on inducing families not currently eligible for AFDC to migrate to a state (i.e., whether people think about "potential safety net" issues). In addition, the growing

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 349 number of foreign immigrants into the United States may be affected differently by this issue than are native-born U.S. residents. Summary Overall, it is clear that cash and near-cash assistance programs have negative effects on such behaviors as work effort, although the effects may often be small. These incentive effects can cause a disjuncture between measured need and the amount of assistance program dollars required to alleviate that need. That is, if people who are provided benefits that are intended to move them out of poverty respond in such ways as working less, the net effect will be to leave them in poverty and to require even more funds to move them out of poverty. Because of such behavioral effects, it is misleading to describe the aggregate "poverty gap" (i.e., the difference between the poverty line and a family's resources, aggregated over all families) as the dollar amount that the government would have to spend to eliminate poverty. Because of behavioral responses, an expenditure that should decrease the poverty gap to zero will almost surely fall short. Moreover, the incentive problem is even broader in that program benefits (whether from public assistance programs or social insurance programs, such as unemployment compensation) may lead to reduced work by beneficiaries, even though the poverty gap or other poverty statistic is not affected. Yet a decision not to provide any type of assistance because there may be some undesired behavioral responses on the part of some program participants is extreme. Such programs as AFDC have their success stories as well as their problems, and, as noted above, behavioral effects, when present, are often small. More fundamentally, there are groups in need—such as children—who are not responsible for their situations but who will suffer if benefits are curtailed. A program designer, then, faces the very difficult task of specifying benefit levels and other program provisions so as to assist needy people but in a manner that does not encourage behaviors that increase program costs or may otherwise be viewed as dysfunctional and, if possible, that encourages functional behaviors. The task is made more difficult by the fact that research findings on incentive effects are often incomplete or inconclusive.9 There is also the problem that other aspects of the environment may undercut efforts to provide incentives for increased self-support: for example, there may not be jobs available in the private sector for welfare recipients. Issues of program incentives have been at the center of policy debate for AFDC, which is directed to families whom the public would like to see increasingly responsible for their own support. Consequently, there has been considerable experimentation with changes in benefit levels and formulas for 9 Indeed, as Citro and Hanushek (1991) note, a major weakness of models that policy analysts use to estimate the likely effects of changes in benefit levels and others features of program design is that the models are not able to properly account for behavioral responses.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 350 calculating disposable income to try to develop effective incentives for recipients to become self-supporting through work and to encourage family stability and better parenting. To date, results show limited effects on such behaviors as work effort from changes in benefit levels and the tax rate on earnings. The evidence is not yet in on more recent state initiatives, such as not increasing benefits when another child is born or reducing benefits if parents do not stay in school or fail to have their children vaccinated. It is important, moreover, to note that other programs besides AFDC raise concerns about incentives. For example, assistance programs for retired or disabled people, such as Social Security and SSI, have negative effects on work effort (see Hurd, 1990; Quinn, Burkhauser, and Myers, 1990; Rust and Phelan, 1993; Wise, 1992). Federal-State Cost Sharing In the United States, federal-state cost-sharing provisions have important effects—not always intended—on program benefit levels and the possibilities for changing those levels. For AFDC, the federal government historically has tried to provide incentives to low-income, low-benefit states to raise benefits by picking up a higher share of assistance program costs in these states. However, there has been little effect on states' behavior: low-benefit states have generally opted to minimize their own budget outlays rather than to raise benefits, and, hence, the variation in benefits across states has remained high (see Peterson and Rom, 1990). Similarly, states have taken advantage of the fact that the Food Stamp Program, for which benefits are funded entirely by the federal government, will partly make up for lower AFDC benefit standards. The current situation in which low-income, low-benefit states receive higher rates of federal reimbursement makes it difficult to devise a politically palatable scheme for raising AFDC benefits to some national minimum standard. A review of one such proposal by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) (1989a), the Partnership Act of 1987 (introduced in the 100th Congress as S. 862 but never enacted), starkly illuminates the problems. The Partnership Act proposed to expand the federal role in financing AFDC and Medicaid and to pay for these expansions by eliminating a number of grant-in-aid programs (e.g., Community Services Block Grants and Urban Mass Transit Research). The act provided for a national minimum AFDC benefit standard that, when combined with food stamps, would ultimately reach 90 percent of the federal poverty line for families with no other income. At the same time, the federal matching rate for AFDC benefits up to the minimum standard would be raised to 90 percent. The evaluation of the federal and state costs of this proposal found that it was not cost-neutral overall as it was intended to be. Rather, if the program had been fully phased in by 1994, CBO (1989a) estimated net costs to the federal government of $38 billion and net savings to the states of $22 billion,

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 351 for a net increase in federal-state government expenditures of $16 billion. More important, CBO found that the effects would be very uneven across states: states in the South would actually incur net costs rather than savings, and savings would be highest for wealthier states. Low-income, low-benefit states would have to pay more than better off, more generous states to bring their benefits up to the federal minimum AFDC standard; moreover, those states, with their already higher matching percentages, would gain less from the increased federal matching rate than better off states. Hence, there would be little incentive for low-income, low-benefit states to support this type of proposal. Of course, there are other ways in which to combine a national minimum benefit standard for AFDC with a provision for federal-state cost sharing. However, the current structure of the program makes it difficult to devise a scheme that does not increase overall program costs or that does not disadvantage some states relative to others. Summary This brief review of some key factors that enter into the design of assistance programs—funding constraints, considerations of the target population, program interactions, incentive effects, and federal-state cost- sharing provisions—makes it clear why it is difficult to link poverty thresholds directly to benefits. To those who are involved in evaluating and designing government assistance programs, our observations will come as no surprise and indeed may seem obvious. Yet we believe it is worth underscoring the point that measuring need, by determining how many people have resources below a reasonable poverty standard, is different from determining the proper societal response to that need. Many factors properly enter into a determination of program benefit standards, including judgements about the extent to which society is prepared to allocate scarce resources to supporting low-income people and the mix of goals that society wants government assistance programs to serve. The critical role of such judgements is the reason that a panel such as ours, chosen for expertise in measurement issues, cannot make recommendations about appropriate benefit levels for specific assistance programs. Ultimately, the determination of appropriate programs and policies to alleviate poverty involves political choices —namely, the consideration of competing public objectives against the constraints of scarce public resources within the framework of a nation's social and political climate and belief system. However, the fact that we do not make a recommendation about national minimum benefit standards for AFDC (or other programs) should not be taken to mean that there is no argument for such a benefit standard. On one hand, it is clear that the states differ in their preferences for spending on public

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 352 assistance, and these preferences should be given weight in any national policy making. On the other hand, there are equity problems in providing needy families with very different levels of public support on the basis of where they happen to live when their economic problems arise. From this perspective, while the proposed poverty measure (or any standard of need) cannot be used by itself to determine benefit levels, it does have a role to play in the policy debate. DETERMINING STATE AFDC STANDARDS OF NEED In most government assistance programs, the benefit standard (i.e., the maximum amount of benefits provided to people with no other income) and the need standard are one and the same: people who are eligible because their countable income falls below the benefit standard are in turn entitled to receive benefits up to the amount of the standard.10 As noted above, the standard for a particular program reflects judgements about a variety of factors, including appropriate levels of need, constraints on available funds, and the desire to provide positive incentives to recipients. AFDC is unique in that federal legislation requires each state to establish a standard of need for families with children who have no other means of support, and, in a separate process, to determine a payment standard, which may be lower than the need standard.11 Both the need standard and the payment standard restrict eligibility for benefits (see below). Furthermore, states may set a maximum benefit amount that is below both the standard of need and the payment standard. Recommendation One might surmise that the need standard, as distinct from the payment standard or maximum benefit, is supposed to represent a type of poverty concept. In this case, one might want to consider the use of the proposed poverty measure as the standard.12 The use of the proposed measure would reduce the current wide disparity in need standards among the states, while recognizing geographic cost-of-living differences. However, it is not clear that the states have typically interpreted the need standard as a poverty concept. Indeed, the role of the need standard in the AFDC program seems 10 Strictly speaking, this statement applies to cash benefit programs (e.g., SSI, veterans' pensions, etc.). Near-cash programs (e.g., food stamps and assisted housing) have a benefit standard that falls below the eligibility standard because the benefit pertains to a single commodity. 11 See Appendix D for details of the AFDC program. 12 As discussed below, 14 states link their need standard to the current poverty guidelines.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 353 murky at best, given that states can, and often do, set benefit standards that fall below their need standards. Since the provision for separately determined need standards exists in the AFDC program, however, we believe it useful to consider the issues involved in the possible use of the proposed poverty measure by the states for this purpose. We begin by describing the basic regulatory framework within which AFDC has operated. We then describe methods of setting need standards that were used in the 1970s and 1980s, current differences in standards and equivalence scales among the states and their relationship to the current poverty line, and trends in need standards and maximum benefits over time. Finally, we discuss the potential relevance of the proposed poverty measure to AFDC need standards. We conclude by encouraging the states to give serious consideration to linking their AFDC need standard to the proposed poverty measure. On balance, that measure would be advantageous for this purpose, although it may need to be modified in some respects. RECOMMENDATION 8.1. The states should consider linking their need standard for the Aid to Families with Dependent Children program to the panel's proposed poverty measure and whether it may be necessary to modify this measure to better serve program objectives. Program Regulations AFDC is a state-administered program with funding provided by both the states and the federal government through a matching provision (see Appendix D). In order to qualify for federal funding, a state must establish a standard of need that defines in monetary amounts the basic needs the state wishes to recognize as appropriate for an assistance standard of living— although neither the components of the standard nor the methods for setting the standard are prescribed by federal law or regulation. The state must apply this standard uniformly and statewide in determining financial eligibility for assistance, but it may vary the standard to account for family size or composition, area cost-of-living differentials, or other factors. States may adopt lower payment standards and maximum benefit amounts than their need standards by such methods as paying a percentage of the difference between the family's income and the need standard, paying a percentage of the need standard, or capping benefits at a specified amount. Recently, a number of states have altered their benefit provisions to satisfy budget constraints and to try to induce recipients to adopt preferred behaviors. As examples, some states no longer provide an additional benefit for an additional child or they condition benefit amounts on such actions as the recipient's obtaining immunization shots for his or her children.13 13 See Wiseman (1993) for a list of these kinds of changes in payment standards for which states had waivers from the federal government approved or pending in 1992.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 354 Over the years, amendments to the law, court decisions, and federal regulations have formally reaffirmed the states' autonomy in deciding AFDC benefit levels. In particular, the 1967 amendments to the Social Security Act affirmed the right of states to set benefit maximums and to apply ''ratable reductions" in order to set benefits lower than the standard of need. The 1967 amendments included a provision to require states to update their need standard to reflect cost-of-living increases since the standard was adopted; however, states were not required to pay benefits consistent with these increases (for an account of the results of this provision, see Rabin, 1970). Although the states have very wide latitude in setting their need standard and benefit levels, federal regulations have always been more specific about the resource side of the ledger for determining AFDC eligibility and benefits (see U.S. House of Representatives, 1994:327-331; Solomon and Neisner, 1993). Currently, to receive AFDC payments, a family must pass two income tests. First, the family's gross income cannot be higher than 185 percent of the state's need standard and the family's net or countable income must not exceed 100 percent of the need standard or payment standard, whichever is lower.14 Standard Setting in the 1970s In 1980, Urban Systems Research & Engineering, Inc. (USR&E) completed a study for the Social Security Administration of AFDC standard setting practices, which included a survey of all 50 states and the District of Columbia and case studies of 11 states. USR&E was critical of state practices with regard to standard setting. In part, this criticism stemmed from the viewpoint expressed in the USR&E study that a standard must be "normative" or "absolute," in the sense that an expert standard of need should be developed for each budget component—independent of expenditure patterns—and then priced out. But as we discuss throughout this report, there are other types of poverty or need standards that merit serious consideration, with advantages and disadvantages. However, USR&E seems justifiably to have concluded that relatively few states in the 1970s were following good standard setting practices, in the sense that they developed their need standard as the result of a well-documented, carefully worked-out process or periodically reviewed their standard to determine whether it should be updated or redefined. USR&E classified the methods originally used by the states to derive their need standard; see Table 8-2. Market Basket Pricing Studies "The market basket approach, which involves the specification and pricing of every component of need, is the traditional method for conceiving and measuring absolute need, and historically it 14 See Appendix D for details on changes to these percentages over time and on other provisions of AFDC with regard to countable income and assets.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 355 TABLE 8-2 State Approaches to Setting AFDC Need Standards in the 1970s and 1980s Standard Setting Method Used in 1970s Used in 1980s Local market basket pricing study Alabama California Colorado Colorado Connecticut Delaware District of Columbia Florida Hawaii Idaho Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kentucky Louisiana Massachusetts Massachusetts Minnesota Missouri Montana Nebraska Nebraska New Jersey Oklahoma Oklahoma Oregon Oregon Pennsylvania South Carolina South Dakota Utah Vermont Washington Washington Expenditure survey (of AFDC recipients) New Mexico North Carolina Ohio Tennessee Texas Virginia BLS lower level budget (as is or modified) Maine Maine Maryland New York New York North Carolina Pennsylvania Tennessee Utah Wisconsin Wisconsin Multiplier or expenditure ratio Illinois Montana Wyoming Combination Georgia Iowa

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 356 Standard Setting Method Used in 1970s Used in 1980s Combination—continued Kansas Michigan Vermont West Virginia Legislative determination Maryland Michigan North Dakota Average payment New Hampshire New Jersey Rhode Island Poverty guidelines (as is or modified) Alabama Arizona Arkansas Delaware Florida Georgia Hawaii Indiana Kentucky Mississippi Nevada New Mexico Ohio South Carolina Arbitrary or not available Alaska Alaska Arizona Arkansas California (N.A.) Connecticut District of Columbia Kansas Louisiana Minnesota (N.A.) Mississippi Missouri Nevada New Hampshire North Dakota Rhode Island South Dakota Texas (N.A.) Virginia West Virginia Wyoming SOURCE: Data from Urban Systems Research & Engineering (1980:Exhibits 1 and 2); Larin and Porter (1992:xii).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 357 has been the most popular basis for AFDC need standards" (Urban Systems Research & Engineering, 1980:8); 21 states reported using this approach. However, only three states had standards that were based on pricing studies conducted in the last 10 years (i.e., in 1969-1979), and only one state had updated its standard regularly on the basis of repeated pricing studies to account for cost-of-living increases. USR&E criticized (perhaps too harshly) the practice in the more recent market basket studies of using expenditure surveys to determine the shelter component of the need standard rather than developing a normative standard for shelter and then pricing it out. Expenditure Surveys Six states reported basing their standard on expenditure surveys that were limited to AFDC recipients. USR&E properly criticized this approach as tautological, in that the population for determining the "standard" was based on current program participants. Lower Level Budget Five states reported adapting the lower level family budget of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) as the basis for their need standards, and all of these states had done so as of 1969 or later. USR&E noted correctly that the BLS budgets represented a combination of normative standards and actual expenditure patterns. The states using the BLS lower level budget generally deleted categories they deemed "inappropriate," either on judgemental grounds (e.g., alcoholic beverages) or on grounds that other programs covered the expenditure (e.g., medical care). However, only two of the five states had regularly updated their need standard. Other One state used a multiplier approach similar to the Orshansky method for deriving the poverty line; six states used a combination of methods; and twelve states used completely arbitrary methods or methods that could not be ascertained in the USR&E survey. Standard Setting in the 1980s The Congressional Research Service regularly tracks changes in the level of the states' need standards and benefit levels (see, e.g., Solomon, 1991; Solomon and Neisner, 1993), but little information was obtained about standard setting practices in the 1980s until recently. In 1992, the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities completed a study for the Administration on Children and Families of AFDC standard setting practices in the late 1980s. This report (Larin and Porter, 1992) was prepared to fulfill the requirement in the 1988 Family Support Act that the states evaluate their AFDC need standard at least once every 3 years and report the results to the Secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS). In early 1991 HHS sent the states a questionnaire asking for information on how each state's need standard in effect as of October 1, 1990, was developed, the relationship between the state's need standard and benefit

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 358 levels, and any changes in the need standard over the preceding 3 years. The Center on Budget and Policy Priorities analyzed the questionnaire responses (California, Minnesota, and Texas did not respond). Larin and Porter (1992:5) conclude, as did USR&E in its earlier study, that "the majority of states cannot demonstrate that their need standards represent an amount of money necessary to purchase basic necessities." Larin and Porter document and evaluate six types of methods for setting AFDC need standards by the states in effect as of 1990 (see Table 8-2): Federal Poverty Guidelines Fourteen states reported relating their need standard in some way to the HHS poverty guidelines.15 Of these, four states reported using the HHS poverty guidelines as is. Ten states modified the guidelines in such ways as subtracting the cost of the Thrifty Food Plan, subtracting average food stamp and Medicaid benefits, subtracting the cost of "nonessential commodities," setting their need standard as a percentage of the guidelines, or allowing their need standard to decline as a percentage of the guidelines because of not adjusting for inflation. BLS Lower Level Budget or Living Standard Six states reported using the BLS lower level budget or living standard—last published in 1982 and developed with expenditure data from the early 1960s—as the basis for their need standards. (Another state was considering the use of a modified lower level budget for its need standard, and the welfare department in another state develops a modified lower level budget as guidance for the state legislature.) Two of the six states modified the BLS standard (e.g., by omitting men's haircuts, household supplies, and occupational costs, as well as making changes to other components of the lower level budget). These states have priced the various budget components by using BLS data or conducting local price surveys; however, none of them has adjusted the standard to keep pace with inflation. Local Market Basket Surveys Fourteen states reported basing their need standard on local market basket surveys, but many of these states have not conducted such a survey recently. Expenditure Ratio (or Multiplier Method) One state reported using Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) data to determine a ratio of all expenditures, other than housing, to apply to the cost of the Thrifty Food Plan. Housing standards were calculated separately on the basis of the actual housing costs of AFDC recipients, with three different standards used for different regions of the state. Another state reported a similar type of method, but developed its multiplier on the basis of CEX data for the lowest quintile of the household income distribution. 15 The HHS poverty guidelines represent a smoothed version of the official poverty thresholds.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 359 Legislative Determination Three states reported that need standards are set by their legislatures on the basis of budgetary considerations. Average Payment Three states reported that they developed need standards in the early 1970s that represented average AFDC payment levels by family size. (AFDC benefits at that time were determined on a discretionary basis by caseworkers according to the particular circumstances of each recipient family.) Unknown Methods Six states "are unable to document how their need standards were originally constructed, either because records are incomplete or lost or because their standards seem to have been set arbitrarily with no reference to living costs" (Larin and Porter, 1992:17). Comparing Larin and Porter (1992) with USR&E (1980), one finds that many states reported using a different method in 1990 than in 1980; see Table 8-2. Only 10 states appear to have used the same method in both decades: Maine, New York, and Wisconsin consistently reported using a variation of the BLS lower level budget, and Colorado, Idaho, Massachusetts, Nebraska, Oklahoma, Oregon, and Washington consistently reported using the market basket pricing method.16 Perhaps the most important change is that 14 states now relate their need standard explicitly to the HHS poverty guidelines. Differences Among States Differences in Need Standards and Benefits As noted above, AFDC need standards vary widely among the states (see Table 8-1). In January 1994, the need standards for the 50 states and the District of Columbia varied from $1,648 per month in New Hampshire to $320 in Indiana, with a median value of $574, a mean value of $655, and a coefficient of variation of 41 percent. The maximum AFDC benefit exhibited almost as much dispersion, although the addition of food stamps reduced the dispersion somewhat. In a historical analysis of AFDC benefits, Peterson and Rom (1990: Table 1-1) found that a high degree of variation in benefit levels has always characterized the states. They determined that the coefficient of variation ranged 16 Inferences about standard setting methods across decades cannot be made with certainty. USR&E and Larin and Porter provide conflicting accounts for some states: for example, Arizona is reported as "unknown method" in USR&E, but in Larin and Porter, Arizona is reported as having previously used a variant of the BLS lower level budget and as currently using the HHS poverty guidelines. Similarly, Missouri is reported as "unknown method" in USR&E, but in Larin and Porter, Missouri is reported as having conducted market basket pricing studies in 1969 and 1975. Also, the "average payment" method that Larin and Porter say that several states adopted in the early 1970s is not one of the methods identified in the USR&E study.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 360 between 32 and 35 percent for the average monthly AFDC payment for 1940-1990 and between 34 and 37 percent for the maximum benefit for a four- person family for 1960-1990. The coefficient of variation was smaller for the maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefit, ranging between 16 and 21 percent for a four-person family for 1970-1990. In looking at the relationship of the maximum AFDC benefit to the need standard in January 1994 (see Table 8-1), 11 states paid a maximum benefit that represented 100 percent of their need standard; 23 states paid between 50 and 99 percent of their need standard (the median state paid 66 percent of its need standard); and the remaining 17 states paid less than 50 percent of their need standard, including 6 states that paid less than 33 percent of their need standard. In looking at the adequacy of AFDC need standards and benefits against the official poverty threshold, 8 states had need standards in January 1994 that were at or above the 1993 official average weighted poverty threshold for a family of three, and 12 states had need standards that were between 70 and 99 percent of the poverty level; see Table 8-3. The remainder had need standards that were below 70 percent of the poverty level. In no state did the maximum AFDC benefit exceed the poverty level, and in only two states did the maximum benefit exceed 70 percent of the poverty level. With the addition of food stamps, the maximum combined benefit exceeded the poverty level in 2 states and was between 70 and 99 percent of the poverty level in 22 states. In looking at the disparities in AFDC need standards and benefit levels, one obvious question is whether they are related to differences in needs and costs of living across states. We constructed an index of the adjustments by state to a national poverty threshold that would result from taking account of differences in the cost of housing. We analyzed 1990 census data to determine cost-of-housing index values by state (relative to a national value of 1.00) and then adjusted each index value downwards by a factor reflecting the proportion that shelter costs (including utilities) represent of the proposed poverty thresholds. (The methodology was the same that we used to determine adjusted cost-of-housing index values by region and size of metropolitan area for the statistical poverty measure; see Chapter 3). We also constructed an index of state median family income from 1990 census tabulations (Bureau of the Census, no date(b)) relative to 1.00 for the average median family income across the states. Not surprisingly, the index of state-adjusted poverty thresholds shows less variation than does the index of median family income; see Table 8-4. The state-adjusted poverty threshold index values range from 24 percent above to 15 percent below the national average, with a coefficient of variation of 10 percent.17 The median family income index values range from 17 The coefficient of variation of 10 percent for the state-adjusted poverty threshold index is similar to that of 8 percent for a state cost-of-living index developed by Peterson and Rom

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 361 TABLE 8-3 AFDC Need Standards, Maximum AFDC Benefits, and Maximum Combined AFDC and Food Stamp Benefits for a Family of Three, as a Percentage of the 1993 Weighted Average Monthly Poverty Threshold, January 1994 Percent of Poverty Threshold State AFDC Need Maximum AFDC Maximum Standard Benefit Combined AFDC/ Food Stamp Benefit Alabama 70 17 48 Alaska 81 77 101 Arizona 100 36 67 Arkansas 73 21 52 California 74 63 86 Colorado 44 37 67 Connecticut 71 71 91 Delaware 35 35 66 District of Columbia 74 44 72 Florida 103 32 62 Georgia 44 29 60 Hawaii 103 64 103 Idaho 103 33 64 Illinois 93 38 69 Indiana 33 30 61 Iowa 88 44 72 Kansas 45 45 74 Kentucky 55 24 54 Louisiana 69 20 51 Maine 58 44 72 Maryland 53 38 69 Massachusetts 60 60 83 Michigana 57 48 75 Minnesota 55 55 80 Mississippi 38 13 43 Missouri 88 30 61 Montana 53 42 71 Nebraska 38 38 68 Nevada 73 36 67 New Hampshire 172 57 81 New Jersey 103 44 73 New Mexico 37 37 67 New York b 60 60 85 North Carolina 57 28 59 North Dakota 43 43 71 Ohio 92 36 66 Oklahoma 49 34 64 Oregon 48 48 78 Pennsylvania 64 44 72 Rhode Island 58 58 86

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 362 Percent of Poverty Threshold State AFDC Need Maximum AFDC Maximum Standard Benefit Combined AFDC/ Food Stamp Benefit South Carolina 46 21 52 South Dakota 51 43 72 Tennessee 44 19 50 Texas 60 19 50 Utah 58 43 71 Vermont 117 68 88 Virginia 41 37 67 Washington 121 57 84 West Virginia 52 26 57 Wisconsin 67 54 79 Wyoming 70 38 68 Mean 67 41 70 Median 60 38 69 Range 35–172 13–77 43–103 Coefficient of 39.9% 36.4% 18.6% variationc SOURCE: U.S. House of Representatives (1994:366-367). NOTE: The 1993 weighted average monthly poverty threshold for a family of three was $960 (the Census Bureau's annual figure of $11,521, divided by 12); this threshold was increased by 25 percent for Alaska and by 15 percent for Hawaii (as is done for the poverty guidelines but not the official thresholds). a The values apply to Wayne County. b The values apply to New York City. c The standard deviation of the distribution as a percentage of the mean value. 43 percent above to 29 percent below the national average with a coefficient of variation of 17 percent. We then divided each state's AFDC need standard, maximum benefit, and combined maximum AFDC and food stamp benefit as of January 1994 by the appropriate state-adjusted poverty threshold index value and the appropriate median family income index value.18 If differences in the cost of living (1990: Table 1-2). Their index averaged cost-of-living indicators for 1985 developed by the American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association for all the cities in each state, weighted by city population size. 18 State median family income (or a state-adjusted poverty threshold) could have changed between the 1990 census and January 1994; however, the results of the same set of calculations using January 1991 values for AFDC need standards, maximum benefits, and combined maximum AFDC and food stamp benefits were very similar to those reported for the January 1994 values.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 363 TABLE 8-4 State Median Family Income and State-Adjusted Poverty Thresholds under the Panel's Proposed Measure State Index for State Median Index for State-Adjusted Family Income Poverty Thresholds with the Proposed Measure Alabama 0.835 0.881 Alaska 1.355 1.102 Arizona 0.936 1.017 Arkansas 0.0739 0.873 California 1.180 1.178 Colorado 1.046 0.973 Connecticut 1.431 1.188 Delaware 1.172 1.066 District of Columbia 1.055 1.112 Florida 0.937 1.049 Georgia 0.976 0.993 Hawaii 1.256 1.243 Idaho 0.858 0.862 Illinois 1.126 1.020 Indiana 0.992 0.949 Iowa 0.921 0.903 Kansas 0.959 0.926 Kentucky 0.787 0.874 Louisiana 0.766 0.902 Maine 0.943 1.029 Maryland 1.310 1.106 Massachusetts 1.291 1.191 Michigan 1.066 0.998 Minnesota 1.074 1.023 Mississippi 0.712 0.853 Missouri 0.927 0.929 Montana 0.816 0.865 Nebraska 0.920 0.908 Nevada 1.043 1.078 New Hampshire 1.211 1.122 New Jersey 1.385 1.202 New Mexico 0.804 0.922 New York 1.156 1.078 North Carolina 0.918 0.940 North Dakota 0.836 0.872 Ohio 1.000 0.955 Oklahoma 0.831 0.883 Oregon 0.941 0.964 Pennsylvania 1.014 0.987 Rhode Island 1.140 1.099 South Carolina 0.897 0.936 South Dakota 0.804 0.872 Tennessee 0.860 0.920

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 364 State Index for State Median Index for State-Adjusted Family Income Poverty Thresholds with the Proposed Measure Texas 0.919 0.963 Utah 0.967 0.900 Vermont 1.012 1.060 Virginia 1.112 1.023 Washington 1.071 1.011 West Virginia 0.745 0.846 Wisconsin 1.021 0.965 Wyoming 0.937 0.863 U.S. average 1.000 1.000 Range 0.712–1.431 0.846–1.243 Coefficient of variationa 17.3% 10.3% NOTE: See text and Chapter 3 for explanation of construction of the indexes. a The standard deviation of a distribution as a percentage of the mean value. across states (as proxied by cost-of-housing differences in the poverty threshold) are the only reason for the differences in need standards and benefit levels, then the calculation with state-adjusted poverty threshold index values should result in the same (or close to the same) dollar amounts of the need standard and maximum benefit in all states. In other words, the amounts in high- cost, high-benefit states would decrease to the mean and the amounts in low- cost, low-benefit states would increase to the mean. The same reasoning applies to the calculation with state median family income index values. These patterns do not occur. There is only a modest effect on the variation across states in AFDC need standards when differences in the cost of living or median family income are taken out of the dollar amounts: the coefficient of variation is reduced from 41 percent to 37 percent; see Table 8-5. For maximum AFDC benefits and maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefits, there is a somewhat greater reduction in the variation across states: the coefficient of variation for maximum AFDC benefits is reduced from 40 percent to 29-33 percent, and the coefficient of variation for maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefits is reduced from 22 percent to 15-16 percent. However, even in the case of maximum combined AFDC and food stamp benefits, significant variation remains that cannot be explained by differences in cost of living or income levels across the states.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 365 TABLE 8-5 Mean and Distribution of State AFDC Need Standards, Maximum AFDC Benefits, and Maximum Combined AFDC and Food Stamp Benefits for a Family of Three, as Reported by the States and as Adjusted for Differences in Income and Cost of Housing, January 1994, in Dollars As Adjusted by an Index for Statistic As Reported State Median State-Adjusted Family Income Poverty Thresholda AFDC Need Standards Mean 655 658 657 Range 320–1,648 288–1,361 317–1,469 Standard deviationb 267 240 242 Coefficient of 40.7% 36.5% 36.8% variationc AFDC Maximum Benefits Mean 396 389 394 Range 120–923 169–681 141–838 Standard deviation 156 113 130 Coefficient of variation 39.5% 29.2% 33.1% AFDC and Food Stamp Maximum Benefits Mean 675 677 679 Range 415–1,208 505–892 521–1,096 Standard deviation 147 98 111 Coefficient of variation 21.8% 14.5% 16.3% NOTE: Data derived from Tables 8-1 and 8-4; see text for description of calculations. a The state-adjusted poverty threshold takes account of state differences in cost of housing adjusted for the share that shelter costs (including utilities) represent in the panel's proposed poverty budget. b The value that when added to or subtracted from the mean includes about two-thirds of the observations (states). c The standard deviation as a percentage of the mean value. Differences in Equivalence Scales Equivalence scales—the proportion by which benefits to the AFDC unit are increased for each added child—also vary across states; see Table 8-6.19 Data are available on the maximum AFDC benefit by family size as of January 1994 for the 50 states and the District of Columbia, ranging from the basic two- person unit (parent or other caretaker and child) through the six-person unit 19 As noted above, some states do not currently pay benefits for additional children beyond the first or second, as an intended deterrent to continued childbearing on the part of AFDC recipients.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 366 TABLE 8-6 Equivalence Scale Implicit in Maximum AFDC Benefits for Two-Person Through Six-Person Families, January 1994 Amount Added to Two-Person (One-Adult/One-Child) Benefit (1.00) for Each Added Child State Second Third Fourth Fifth Average, Child (3- Child (4- Child (5- Child (6- Added Person Person Person Person Child Family) Family) Family) Family) Alabama .197 .219 .226 .197 .210 Alaska .124 .124 .124 .124 .124 Arizona .262 .258 .258 .262 .260 Arkansas .259 .265 .241 .278 .261 California .239 .237 .206 .208 .222 Colorado .271 .271 .286 .279 .277 Connecticut .239 .204 .184 .193 .205 Delaware .252 .256 .252 .256 .254 District of .273 .282 .236 .315 .277 Columbia Florida .257 .253 .257 .253 .255 Georgia .191 .213 .204 .136 .186 Hawaii .260 .260 .260 .260 .260 Idaho .263 .259 .263 .259 .261 Illinois .369 .175 .265 .224 .258 Indiana .258 .253 .258 .253 .255 Iowa .180 .191 .147 .172 .172 Kansas .219 .193 .173 .173 .190 Kentucky .163 .291 .245 .219 .230 Louisiana .377 .319 .312 .283 .322 Maine .340 .346 .340 .343 .342 Maryland .280 .262 .245 .178 .241 Massachusetts .191 .183 .189 .193 .189 Michigan .237 .280 .259 .358 .284 Minnesota .217 .204 .174 .174 .192 Mississippi .250 .250 .250 .250 .250 Missouri .248 .214 .197 .184 .210 Montana .261 .261 .261 .261 .261 Nebraska .242 .242 .242 .242 .242 Nevada .208 .208 .208 .205 .207 New Hampshire .143 .131 .125 .168 .142 New Jersey .317 .199 .199 .199 .228 New Mexico .261 .261 .258 .261 .261 New York .233 .235 .241 .179 .222 North Carolina .153 .106 .114 .106 .120 North Dakota .228 .276 .204 .177 .221 Ohio .222 .287 .258 .201 .242 Oklahoma .291 .311 .271 .271 .286 Oregon .165 .266 .241 .241 .228 Pennsylvania .276 .282 .282 .242 .270 Rhode Island .234 .174 .174 .200 .195

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 367 Amount Added to Two-Person (One-Adult/One-Child) Benefit (1.00) for Each Added Child State Second Third Fourth Fifth Average, Child (3- Child (4- Child (5- Child (6- Added Person Person Person Person Child Family) Family) Family) Family) South .258 .252 .258 .252 .255 Carolina South Dakota .133 .128 .130 .130 .130 Tennessee .303 .289 .268 .289 .287 Texas .165 .234 .158 .241 .199 Utah .247 .211 .202 .169 .207 Vermont .190 .147 .162 .104 .151 Virginia .204 .190 .265 .102 .190 Washington .241 .218 .223 .230 .228 West .239 .313 .239 .264 .264 Virginia Wisconsin .175 .227 .207 .132 .185 Wyoming .125 .094 .188 .188 .148 Mean .234 .231 .224 .217 .227 Median .239 .242 .241 .219 .228 Range .124-.377 .094-.346 .114-.340 .102-.358 .120-.342 Coefficient 24.0% 24.2% 22.0% 27.1% 21.5% of variationa Current .169 .307 .229 .197 .226 poverty measure Panel's .295 .275 .256 .248 .269 proposed equivalence scale— alternative 1b Panel's .255 .227 .206 .199 .222 proposed equivalence scale— alternative 2c NOTE: Data calculated from U.S. House of Representatives (1994:368-369) for each state; calculated from Bureau of the Census (1993c: Table A) for the current poverty measure. a The standard deviation of a distribution as a percentage of the mean value. b Scale economy factor of 0.75. c Scale economy factor of 0.65.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 368 (basic unit plus four added children). At one extreme, Louisiana increases its $138 benefit for the basic two-person unit by 32 percent on average ($44) for each additional child. At the other extreme, Alaska increases its much higher benefit of $821 for the basic unit by only 12 percent ($102) for each additional child. The median value that is added on average to the basic unit benefit for each added child is 23 percent.20 In looking at the shape of the equivalence scales for AFDC benefits, five states have a regular pattern whereby, within 1 or 2 percentage points, they add the same amount to the basic unit benefit for each additional child; 10 other states have a regular pattern within 6 percentage points. Ten states have a declining pattern, whereby they add progressively less for each child after the second or third. In contrast, 10 states add more for the third and fourth child than for either the second or fifth. Finally, 16 states have erratic patterns. For instance, they may add more for the third and fifth children than for the second and fourth. In this, they resemble the equivalence scale implicit in the current U.S. poverty measure, in which the second child adds 17 percent to the two- person (one-adult/one-child) poverty threshold, the third child adds 31 percent, the fourth child adds 23 percent, and the fifth child adds 20 percent.21 The type of equivalence scale that we recommend for the poverty measure would increase the benefit for a one-adult/one-child family the most for the second child, with declining percentages for each additional child to reflect household economies of scale. Depending on the value of the scale economy factor, our proposed equivalence scale would add an average of 27 percent (using a factor of 0.75) or an average of 22 percent (using a factor of 0.65) to the basic unit benefit for each additional child. Trends in Need Standards and Benefits Looking at trends over the last two decades, it appears that relatively few states have increased their need standard or maximum benefit to keep up with inflation. Relatively few states have statutes that require them to adjust their standards for inflation, and even those states that have such requirements do not always heed them in periods of budget stringency. As of 1988, seven states had statutory requirements for adjusting their need standard to keep up with inflation, one state had a requirement to update its benefit level, and three 20 Note that the ratios of the benefit for an added child to the benefit for the basic AFDC unit are not comparable to equivalence scales expressed in terms of a one-person family or house-hold. Such scales can be constructed for January 1994 from U.S. House of Representatives (1994:368-369). 21 The average value added per child to the U.S. poverty threshold for the two-person (one- adult/one-child) family is 23 percent, the same as the median value for the 50 states and the District of Columbia.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 369 states had requirements to update both their need standard and their benefit levels; only one state apparently had a requirement to periodically reevaluate the need standard itself (Center on Social Welfare Policy and Law, 1988). In the 1970s, inflation rose significantly—by 111 percent (as measured by the CPI-U). Yet only four states increased the value of their need standard in real dollar terms during this period, and the median state saw its need standard decline by 38 percent (in real terms); see Table 8-7. The decline in real terms in the value of the maximum benefit in the median state was somewhat less—26 percent; see Table 8-8. As a result, the number of states paying ''full need" doubled over the period (from 14 to 29 states), and the number paying 70 percent or more of need increased from 33 to 44 states. In the 1980s, inflation moderated—increasing by 63 percent—and 26 states increased the value of their need standard to keep up with or exceed the rate of inflation. In the median state the need standard remained constant in real dollar terms. Many states updated their need standard after the passage of the 1981 Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act, which included a provision that families could not be eligible for AFDC benefits if their gross income exceeded 150 percent (later raised to 185 percent) of the state need standard. In this way, states were able to avoid denying eligibility to families with earnings who would otherwise have been above the gross income cutoff although below the net income cutoff after allowable deductions. However, states did not necessarily update their benefit level to match: for example, Alabama doubled its need standard between 1980 and 1985 but did not raise its maximum benefit (see U.S. House of Representatives, 1991:601-605). Indeed, in the median state the maximum benefit declined by 22 percent. From 1980 to 1991 the number of states paying full need dropped from 29 to 16, and the number paying 70 percent or more of need dropped from 44 to 27 states. In looking at the whole time span, the need standard declined in real terms in the median state by 33 percent from 1970 to 1991, and the maximum benefit declined in real terms by 38 percent.22 One consequence of declining AFDC benefits over the period was that food stamps (which are indexed yearly for inflation) accounted for an increasing proportion of the combined AFDC and food stamps benefit. This change reduced the financial burden on the states, since the federal government pays the full cost of food stamps. Conclusions Clearly, a persistent characteristic of the AFDC program has been the great variation in need standards (and benefit levels) among the states—variation 22 The median state's need standard remained approximately constant in real terms from January 1991 to January 1994, while the median state's maximum AFDC benefit continued to decline (see U.S. House of Representatives, 1994: Tables 10-13, 10-14).

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 370 TABLE 8-7 AFDC Need Standards for a Family of Three, July 1970, July 1980, and January 1991, in Constant (January 1991) Dollars AFDC Need Standard (in Percentage Change January 1991 dollars) State July July Jan. 1970– 1980– 1970– 1970 1980 1991 1980 1991 1991 Alabama 635 313 603 -51 93 -5 Alaska 1,208 745 891 -38 20 -26 Arizona 731 380 621 -48 63 -15 Arkansas 514 381 705 -26 85 37 California 1,211 782 694 -35 -11 -43 Colorado 666 473 421 -29 -11 -37 Connecticut 976 774 680 -21 -12 -30 Delaware 845 434 338 -49 -22 -60 District of 790 642 712 -19 11 -10 Columbia Florida 652 318 880 -51 177 35 Georgia 611 315 424 -48 35 -31 Hawaii 780 763 1,012 -2 33 30 Idaho 821 605 554 -26 -8 -33 Illinois 800 469 811 -41 73 1 Indiana 938 500 320 -47 -36 -66 Iowa 852 587 497 -31 -15 -42 Kansas 838 562 409 -33 -27 -51 Kentucky 718 306 526 -57 72 -27 Louisiana 593 655 658 10 0 11 Maine 956 676 652 -29 -4 -32 Maryland 859 440 562 -49 28 -35 Massachusetts 925 618 539 -33 -13 -42 Michigana 756 693 586 -8 -15 -22 Minnesota 883 680 532 -23 -22 -40 Mississippi 697 359 368 -48 3 -47 Missouri 983 509 312 -48 -39 -68 Montana 762 422 453 -45 7 -41 Nebraska 969 505 364 -48 -28 -62 Nevada 928 465 550 -50 18 -41 New Hampshire 904 564 516 -38 -9 -43 New Jersey 1,042 587 424 -44 -28 -59 New Mexico 576 359 310 -38 -14 -46 New Yorkb 963 642 577 -33 -10 -40 North Carolina 580 313 544 -46 74 -6 North Dakota 800 544 401 -32 -26 -50 Ohio 714 564 776 -21 38 9 Oklahoma 618 460 471 -26 2 -24 Oregon 790 460 444 -42 -3 -44 Pennsylvania 914 541 614 -41 13 -33 Rhode Island 790 554 554 -30 0 -30 South Carolina 559 305 440 -45 44 -21 South Dakota 911 523 385 -43 -26 -58 Tennessee 618 292 412 -53 41 -33

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 371 AFDC Need Standard (in Percentage Change January 1991 dollars) State July July Jan. 1970– 1980– 1970– 1970 1980 1991 1980 1991 1991 Texas 683 253 574 -63 127 -16 Utah 769 782 537 2 -31 -30 Vermont 990 1,092 1,029 10 -6 4 Virginia 828 561 393 -32 -30 -53 Washington 890 747 983 -16 32 10 West Virginia 759 448 497 -41 11 -35 Wisconsin 738 851 647 15 -24 -12 Wyoming 849 513 674 -40 31 -21 Mean 807 536 566 -34 13 -28 Median 800 513 544 -38 0 -33 Range 514– 253– 310– (-63)– (-39)– (-68)– 1,211 1,092 1,029 15 177 37 Coefficient 18.9% 31.7% 31.3% 51.8% 337.3% 88.7% of variationc NOTES: Data calculated from U.S. House of Representatives (1991:602-605). The adjustment to constant January 1991 dollars was made using the values for the urban Consumer Price Index (CPI- U). a The values apply to Wayne County. b The values apply to New York City. c The standard deviation of a distribution as a percentage of the mean value. that considerably exceeds estimated differences in the cost of living across states. Another characteristic has been the absence in many states of systematic procedures for setting and periodically revising the AFDC need standard. A fundamental question is whether the concept of a separate need standard makes sense: most assistance programs do not distinguish between a need standard and the maximum benefit the program will pay to participants with no other source of support. Limits on gross as well as countable income in these programs (e.g., SSI) are set as a function of the benefit standard, and such a practice could be followed in AFDC as well. Urban Systems Research & Engineering (1980:22) argued that the AFDC need standard serves the useful function of a goal or benchmark and that need standards are not an exercise in futility: The systematic derivation and conscientious maintenance of normative standards of need can lead not only to higher need standards, but also to higher payment levels than would be achieved in the absence of any commitment to a realistic benchmark of adequacy [emphasis in original].

TABLE 8-8 AFDC Maximum Benefits for a Family of Three, July 1970, July 1980, and January 1991, in Constant (January 1991) Dollars July 1970 July 1980 January 1991 Percentage Change State Max. Percent of Max. Percent of Max. Percent of 1970– 1980– 1970– AFDC Ben. Need Std. AFDC Ben. Need Std. AFDC Ben. Need Std. 1980 1991 1991 Alabama 224 35 192 61 124 21 -14 -35 -45 Alaska 1,132 94 745 100 891 100 -34 -20 -21 Arizona 476 65 329 87 293 47 -31 -11 -38 Arkansas 307 60 262 69 204 29 -15 -22 -34 California 642 53 771 99 694 100 20 -10 8 Colorado 666 100 473 100 356 85 -29 -25 -47 Connecticut 976 100 774 100 680 100 -21 -12 -30 Delaware 552 65 434 100 338 100 -21 -22 -39 District of 673 85 466 73 428 60 -31 -8 -36 Columbia THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC Florida 393 60 318 100 294 33 -19 -8 -25 Georgia 369 60 267 85 280 66 -28 5 -24 Hawaii 780 100 763 100 632 62 -2 -17 -19 Idaho 728 89 526 87 317 57 -28 -40 -56 Illinois 800 100 469 100 367 45 -41 -22 -54 Indiana 414 44 416 83 288 90 0 -31 -30 Iowa 693 81 587 100 426 86 -15 -27 -39 Kansas 766 91 562 100 409 100 -27 -27 -47 Kentucky 507 71 306 100 228 43 -40 -25 -55 Louisiana 304 51 248 38 190 29 -18 -23 -37 Maine 466 49 456 68 453 69 -2 -1 -3 Maryland 559 65 440 100 406 72 -21 -8 -27 Massachusetts 925 100 618 100 539 100 -33 -13 -42 Michigana 756 100 693 100 525 90 -8 -24 -31 Minnesota 883 100 680 100 532 100 -23 -22 -40 Mississippi 193 28 156 43 120 33 -19 -23 -38 Missouri 359 37 404 80 292 94 13 -28 -19 Montana 697 91 422 100 370 82 -39 -12 -47 372

Nebraska 590 61 505 100 364 100 -14 -28 -38 Nevada 417 45 427 92 330 60 2 -23 -21 New Hampshire 904 100 564 100 516 100 -38 -9 -43 New Jersey 1,042 100 587 100 424 100 -44 -28 -59 New Mexico 514 89 359 100 310 100 -30 -14 -40 New Yorkb 963 100 642 100 577 100 -33 -10 -40 North Carolina 500 86 313 100 272 50 -37 -13 -46 North Dakota 735 92 544 100 401 100 -26 -26 -45 Ohio 555 78 429 76 334 43 -22 -22 -40 Oklahoma 524 85 460 100 341 72 -12 -26 -35 Oregon 635 80 460 100 444 100 -28 -3 -30 Pennsylvania 914 100 541 100 421 69 -41 -22 -54 Rhode Island 790 100 554 100 554 100 -30 0 -30 South Carolina 293 52 210 69 210 48 -28 0 -28 South Dakota 911 100 523 100 385 100 -43 -26 -58 THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC Tennessee 386 62 199 68 195 47 -48 -2 -49 Texas 511 75 189 75 184 32 -63 -3 -64 Utah 604 79 587 75 402 75 -3 -32 -33 Vermont 921 93 802 73 679 66 -13 -15 -26 Virginia 776 94 505 90 354 90 -35 -30 -54 Washington 890 100 747 100 531 54 -16 -29 -40 West Virginia 393 52 336 75 249 50 -15 -26 -37 Wisconsin 635 86 724 85 517 80 14 -29 -19 Wyoming 735 87 513 100 360 53 -30 -30 -51 Mean 635 78 480 89 393 72 -23 -18 -37 Median 635 85 469 100 367 72 -26 -22 -38 Range 193–1,132 28–100 157–807 38–100 120–891 21–100 (-63)–20 (-40)–20 (-64)–8 Coefficiant of variationc 35.5% 27.0% 35.6% 17.3% 39.5% 34.7% 71.4% 65.2% 37.1% NOTES: Data calculated from U.S. House of Representatives (1991:602-605). The adjustment to constant January 1991 dollars was made using the CPI-U. a The values apply to Wayne County. b The values apply to New York City. c The standard deviation of a distribution as a percentage of the mean value. 373

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 374 USR&E based this argument on the behavior of the subset of states that either made a conscientious effort during the 1970s to set normative standards or, although not having recently established a systematically derived need standard, had committed themselves to maintaining the value of their need standard in real terms. These states as a group increased both their need standard and their benefit level more than other states in the 1969-1979 period. However, it seems to us as likely or more likely that a common set of factors (e.g., a more supportive attitude toward welfare programs) explains the propensity to raise both need and benefit standards in some states rather than that higher need standards in and of themselves cause states to raise their benefits. We do not offer a recommendation about the merits of having a separate need standard in the AFDC program, although we are among those who find the concept of questionable utility. Welfare policy is currently the subject of intense debate, and the AFDC program as it has operated historically may likely change in significant ways, perhaps rendering moot the issue of the soundness or adequacy of the need standard for the existing program. However, given that current law requires states to set need standards (and allows them to have lower benefit standards), our concern is whether it makes sense for states to adopt the proposed poverty measure in place of their own standard. A recent development in standard setting practices with relevance to this issue is that, in the past decade, 14 states have explicitly geared their need standard to the current poverty guidelines, which derive from the official thresholds. In many of these states, the link is more theoretical than actual, in that the need standard, either by law or regulation or because of failure to adjust for inflation, is a small fraction of the poverty guidelines. In other states, the definition of the poverty guidelines has been altered to exclude some types of consumption. Overall, however, a growing number of states are finding it convenient to link their AFDC need standard to the poverty guidelines in some fashion. We recommend that states that tie their AFDC need standard to the current poverty measure consider the use of the proposed measure instead, and we encourage all of the states to make a similar assessment. The Family Support Act requires states to review their need standard every 3 years and report to HHS. We note that HHS could request the states to complete an assessment that considers the possible use of the proposed poverty measure for inclusion in their next regular reports. An important element of such a review is an assessment of the implications of the proposed measure—both the thresholds and the definition of family resources—in relation to a state's current need standard (whether the poverty guidelines or its own standard) and the rules for determining gross and net income. Also important to consider is whether the proposed measure may need to be modified in one or more respects to be more suitable for program

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 375 purposes. Finally, it is important to keep in mind the need for consistency between the thresholds and the resource definition in whatever measure a state uses. Comparative Advantage of the Proposed Poverty Measure The use of the proposed threshold concept to set state need standards of AFDC would represent an improvement over the current measure in several respects. One improvement relates to the equivalence scale by which the reference family poverty threshold is adjusted to take account of different needs for different types of families: the proposed scale is more reasonable than that embedded in the official thresholds. Another improvement is that the proposed threshold concept incorporates geographic variation in housing costs. For the statistical measure of poverty, we recommended that the thresholds vary by nine regions and several categories of size of metropolitan area within region (see Chapter 3). States may want to use thresholds that are specific to their state as a whole, and it is certainly feasible to develop such thresholds from decennial census data (see Table 8-4). Alternatively, states may want to have thresholds that vary by size of metropolitan area (or other geographic unit) within the state, and it is also feasible to develop such thresholds from census data. We caution against making further distinctions, particularly for small metropolitan or other areas, as the sample sizes underlying the estimates can become uncomfortably small. Thus, for many metropolitan areas under about 125,000 population, there are only 200-300 cases of housing units in the 1990 decennial census data with the specified characteristics that are used to estimate geographic differences in housing costs. The Census Bureau and Bureau of Labor Statistics could assist the states by constructing thresholds by state and by substate area and by providing estimates of the sampling error underlying the geographic indexes. The states could then determine whether there is enough intrastate variation and whether the estimates of that variation are sufficiently reliable to warrant using several different thresholds. Finally, an important improvement is that we propose a consistent budget concept and definition of family resources. Moreover, the proposed resource definition is more congruent with the income definition in the AFDC program than is the current gross money income definition, so it would be more consistent to use the proposed threshold concept in place of the current concept. For example, the AFDC definition of countable income deducts child care and other work expenses. It does not deduct out-of-pocket medical care expenditures, but AFDC recipients are automatically eligible for Medicaid, which limits their out-of-pocket expenditures (although the generosity of the program varies among states). There are also some inconsistencies. For example, the EITC and a few other sources of income may not be counted as

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 376 income in the AFDC program. Also, in-kind benefits are not counted as income (see further discussion below). Overall, however, the income definition in concept (if not necessarily in the specific details, such as the amount allowed for child care or work expenses) is quite consistent with the budget concept that underlies the proposed poverty thresholds and definition of family resources. Problematic Aspects of the Proposed Poverty Measure Program Interactions One issue that arises with the use of the proposed threshold concept (or the current concept, for that matter) is that AFDC is not the only program of basic consumption support for low-income families. Specifically, such programs as food stamps, school meals, public housing, and home energy assistance provide important components of consumption for many AFDC families—kinds of consumption that are included in the need concepts that underlie both the current poverty measure and the proposed alternative. Currently, a few of the states that tie their need standard to the HHS poverty guidelines attempt to take account of interaction effects with other assistance programs by subtracting food or food and medical care costs from the guidelines in order to form their AFDC need standard. However, such adjustments are not necessarily appropriate, even when the need standard would otherwise equal the poverty thresholds.23 With regard to medical care, the official poverty thresholds arguably do not include medical expenses that would be covered by Medicaid or other health insurance; the proposed thresholds do not include such expenses either (see Chapter 4). Hence, to subtract Medicaid from the poverty guidelines—or from thresholds developed under the proposed measure—is to assume that such benefits are fungible and can be used for other needed goods, when this is not generally the case. There is a clearer case for subtracting food stamps from the poverty thresholds to form AFDC need standards, particularly since food stamps are not counted as income for computing AFDC benefits. However, as we noted earlier, the way in which food stamp benefits are computed—specifically, the assumption that 30 percent of countable income (including AFDC benefits) will be available for food consumption—means that it is not straightforward to determine an appropriate adjustment. To subtract the entire value of the Thrifty Food Plan from the poverty thresholds would likely result in too great 23 Logically, such adjustments should not even be considered when the need standard is set at a fraction of the poverty thresholds, as is the case in a number of states. See Larin and Porter (1992) for a discussion of the problems in adjusting the current poverty guidelines to try to account for program interactions.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 377 a reduction in the AFDC need standard; how much less than that amount might be appropriate is open to question. Clearly, the issue of program interactions is a very difficult one. It may make most sense for the states to think of the AFDC need standard as a global standard, and then address program interaction questions in determining AFDC benefit levels. Implications of Updating for Costs and Caseloads Another important issue with the possible use of the proposed poverty measure to determine AFDC need standards concerns the proposed procedure for updating the thresholds. As we have stressed, thresholds developed under that procedure will reflect real increases in basic consumption, not just price changes. The use of thresholds updated in this manner offers the advantage that states would not have to periodically evaluate their need standard for real changes in living standards. Although few states have historically sought to revise their standard on any regular basis, there are some exceptions, and the Family Support Act now requires states to evaluate their need standard at least once every 3 years and to report the results to HHS. However, with the proposed procedure, the states would face concerns about possibly larger caseloads and higher costs compared with the use of the current poverty guidelines (see Chapter 7). One way in which the need standard is linked to eligibility for AFDC—and, hence, potentially to caseloads and the costs associated with changes in caseloads—is through federal law. The effects of this link may be relatively minor because the tie, strictly speaking, is only to gross income. Families with gross incomes that do not exceed 185 percent of the need standard may be eligible, but only if their net income does not exceed the payment standard. Hence, in states that do not raise their payment standard, increases in the need standard that result from the use of the proposed procedure will not necessarily add to caseloads or costs.24 More important effects on costs and caseloads may stem from the links that state laws provide between the need standards and the determination of net income eligibility and benefits. These links are more or less direct, depending on which of several methods a state uses to calculate eligibility and benefits; for some examples of how changes in need standards can affect families' eligibility status and benefits depending on the method used by the state, see Figure 8-1. 24 The adoption of higher need standards could cause some families with very high deductions from gross income to become eligible, but the number is likely to be small. There is evidence that states do not necessarily worry about increased costs from raising their need standard, from their reactions to federal legislation in the early 1980s that limited eligibility to families with gross income below 150 percent of the need standard (subsequently increased to 185%). Many states, including those with low-benefits, raised their need standards but not their benefit levels. This response allowed previously eligible families with high deductions to continue to be eligible but limited any increase in their benefits.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 378 EXAMPLE A: STATEPAYS 100 PERCENT OF DIFFERENCE BETWEEN NEED STANDARD AND COUNTABLE INCOME An increase in the need standard affects the number of eligible families and translates dollar for dollar into an increase in benefits. FAMILY 1: Countable income of $450 per month If need standard is $400 per month, family will be ineligible. If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will be eligible for $50 benefit ($500 - $450). FAMILY 2: Countable income of $350 per month If need standard is $400 per month, family will be eligible for $50 benefit ($400 - $350). If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will be eligible for a benefit increase of $100 per month ($500 - $350 = $150). EXAMPLE B: STATE PAYS FRACTION (50%) OF DIFFERENCE BETWEEN NEED STANDARD AND COUNTABLE INCOME An increase in the need standard affects the number of eligible families but increases benefits only fractionally. FAMILY 1: Countable income of $450 per month If need standard is $400 per month, family will be ineligible. If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will be eligible for $25 benefit (($500 - $450) × 0.50). FAMILY 2: Countable income of $350 per month If need standard is $400 per month, family will be eligible for $25 benefit (($400 - $350) × 0.50). If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will be eligible for a benefit increase of $50 per month (($500 - $350) × 0.50 = $75). FIGURE 8-1 AFDC eligibility and benefits of hypothetical families in states with different eligibility and benefit determination methods. • Example A: A state pays the full difference between the need standard and countable income. In this case, the need standard (which determines gross income eligibility) is the same as the payment standard (which determines net or countable income eligibility), and both are the same as the maximum benefit paid to families with no other income. The link of the need standard to eligibility and benefit levels and hence to caseloads and costs is most obvious in these cases: an increase in the need standard allows families with higher net (as well as gross) incomes to become eligible and, for a given level of countable income, provides a higher level of benefits. • Example B: A state pays a fraction of the difference between the need standard and countable income. In this case, the need standard and the payment standard are the same, but the maximum benefit is lower. Here, there is a direct link of the need standard to eligibility, which means a link to caseloads and the costs associated with changes in caseloads. However, the

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 379 EXAMPLE C: STATE PAYS DIFFERENCE BETWEEN FRACTION (50%) OF NEED STANDARD AND COUNTABLE INCOME An increase in the need standard only fractionally increases the number of eligible families as well as the amount of benefits. FAMILY 1: Countable income of $450 per month If need standard is $800 per month, family will be ineligible ($800 × 0.50 = $400, which is &$450). If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will still be ineligible ($900 × 0.50 = $450, which equals $450). FAMILY 2: Countable income of $350 per month If need standard is $800 per month, family will be eligible for $50 benefit (($800 × 0.50) - $350 = $50). If need standard is increased by $100 per month, family will be eligible for a benefit increase of $50 per month (($900 × 0.50) - $350 = $100). EXAMPLE D: STATE PAYS 100 PERCENT OF DIFFERENCE BETWEEN NEED STANDARD AND COUNTABLE INCOME SUBJECT TO A MAXIMUM BENEFIT An increase in the need standard affects neither the number of eligible families nor benefits unless the maximum benefit is also increased. FAMILY 1: Countable income of $450 per month. If need standard is $400 per month and maximum benefit is $375 per month, family will be ineligible. If need standard is increased by $100 per month but maximum benefit is unchanged, family will still be ineligible. FAMILY 2: Countable income of $350 per month If need standard is $400 per month and maximum benefit is $375 per month, family will be eligible for $25 benefit ($375 - $350). If need standard is increased by $100 per month but maximum benefit is unchanged, family will still be eligible for $25 benefit. link to benefits per case is attenuated because eligible families with a given level of countable income will receive only a fraction of an increase in the need standard. • Example C: A state pays a fraction of the need standard itself. In this case, the need standard exceeds both the payment standard and the maximum benefit. Here, the link of the need standard to both eligibility and benefits is attenuated. • Example D: A state uses one of the three methods listed above to make an initial determination of eligibility and benefits, but then imposes a maximum benefit that is lower than both its need and its payment standards. In this state, increases in the need standard have no effect, practically speaking, on either eligibility or benefit amounts unless the maximum benefit is also increased.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 380 Clearly, each state will need to analyze the possible implications for program costs and caseloads of basing its need standard on poverty thresholds that are developed under the proposed updating procedure. Given the differences among states in methods for determining eligibility and benefits, the states may well come to different conclusions. Effects of Updating on Program Incentives Some states that have a maximum benefit below their need standard provide higher benefits to families with other income, such as earnings or child support, through a ''fill-the-gap" method of calculating benefits. The details of this method vary across states, but the essence is that families are allowed to retain other income without having their AFDC benefit reduced, so long as the total of their benefit and other income does not exceed the need standard (see Larin and Porter, 1992: App). To illustrate, consider a state with a need (and payment) standard and maximum payment of $400 per month (i.e., the state pays 100% of need). In this state, a newly eligible family that has $200 of earnings will receive only $200 in AFDC, as the family's earnings will be subtracted in full from the need standard. But in another state, one that has a maximum benefit of $400 per month but a need (and payment) standard of $600 per month and that allows families to fill the gap, the same family will receive an AFDC benefit of $400 because the family's $200 in earnings will be subtracted from the (higher) need standard. The fill-the-gap approach to benefit calculation is a way to provide incentives to working families. Hence, states that want to provide such incentives may find it attractive to base their need standard on poverty thresholds that are developed under the proposed updating procedure. Summary We have offered a number of reasons that the use of the proposed poverty measure by the states for their AFDC need standard could be advantageous and some areas of concern, principally involving possible effects on program costs and caseloads. We do not want our discussion of budgetary implications to be misinterpreted. We do not intend to argue against the adoption of need standards for the AFDC program that are updated in real terms; indeed, from the perspective of the low-income population, there is much to recommend such a step by the states. However, assistance programs must balance a number of objectives and contend with a number of constraints. We urge that program designers fully evaluate all of the ramifications before deciding to adopt for program purposes a measure that is proposed for statistical purposes. For the AFDC need standard, it is important to note that the states, under current law, have considerable latitude with which to attenuate the link of the

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 381 need standard to eligibility and benefits, by such strategies as setting the payment standard at a fraction of the need standard. Hence, considerations of possible adverse consequences for program costs and caseloads should perhaps weigh less heavily than the advantages of using the proposed poverty measure to set AFDC standards of need. In conclusion, we believe that, on balance, the use of the proposed poverty concept for the purpose of determining AFDC need standards would be beneficial, even if individual states set their need (or benefit) standard at different fractions of the poverty threshold. Use of the poverty thresholds that are developed under the proposed procedure would be generally consistent with the AFDC definition of income and would recognize important interstate differences in living costs within a common framework that would provide a benchmark for evaluating the adequacy of eligibility levels across states.

THE POVERTY MEASURE AND AFDC 382

383 APPENDICES

384

Next: APPENDIX A Dissent »
Measuring Poverty: A New Approach Get This Book
×
Buy Paperback | $75.00 Buy Ebook | $59.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

Each year's poverty figures are anxiously awaited by policymakers, analysts, and the media. Yet questions are increasing about the 30-year-old measure as social and economic conditions change.

In Measuring Poverty a distinguished panel provides policymakers with an up-to-date evaluation of:

  • Concepts and procedures for deriving the poverty threshold, including adjustments for different family circumstances.
  • Definitions of family resources.
  • Procedures for annual updates of poverty measures.

The volume explores specific issues underlying the poverty measure, analyzes the likely effects of any changes on poverty rates, and discusses the impact on eligibility for public benefits. In supporting its recommendations the panel provides insightful recognition of the political and social dimensions of this key economic indicator.

Measuring Poverty will be important to government officials, policy analysts, statisticians, economists, researchers, and others involved in virtually all poverty and social welfare issues.

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!